1000 Alitalia in one shot: so' forti 'sti Amerikani .... (II)

/ Articolo / 1000 Alitalia in one shot: so' forti 'sti Amerikani .... (II)
  • Condividi
I apologize for being so verbose, but while writing I am trying to also clear my mind of its many confusions. Because nFA is a blog read by many people, I am also trying to make the argument at least partially understandable to readers not trained in formal economic theory. A machine translation into the Italian language is available (click the flag), which I hope to turn into readable, instead of laughable, Italian tomorrow.

'<h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'Back to Earth'</h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'

I ended the first part with a puzzle that seemed unsolvable. This was

just to make sure I could keep your attention, because things are not

nearly as bad as I made them appear; at least they are not nearly as

bad when financial markets function "properly" and "normally". Here's

why. As Filippo noted,

the notional amounts are seldom if ever paid: they are used only to

calculate the actual payments taking place between the two

counterparts. Consider the case of a simple interest rate swap on a

notional amount of $100 million. Neither party expects to ever have to

pay $100 million to the other; instead A will pay to B the difference

(0.7%, say) between the fixed and the floating rate in the reference

period, time $100 million, that is $700K, which is a lot less than the

notional. Also, many derivatives often expire without any payment or

only a few payments taking place, other are balanced by the issuing of

similar derivatives with the opposite sign, and so on. Further, for

derivatives traded in organized markets (e.g. futures)

on top of the fact that at settlement one must pay only the net loss

(receive the net gain), the organized exchanges ask for margin deposits

that are proportional to the open positions and force their closure

whenever those margins cannot be reasonably met. In other words, I

wanted to scare my readers a bit ... to drive home a point that Warren Buffet has repeated a number of times and to which everyone, including financial economists, have paid little attention.

The OTC derivatives market allows for the establishment of contractual

obligations between financial institutions that may be impossible to

satisfy, even in principle. In particular, OTC derivatives allow for

the creation of a "pyramid" of financial promises that cannot possibly

be satisfied because the amount to be paid, in certain states of the

world, is larger than the value of total world wealth in those same

states of the world. Call this point 1.

In models where individual portfolios are fully observable, beliefs

over future states of the world are common (or, at least, they have a

common support) and markets are dynamically complete, the situation

conjectured in point 1 is impossible. This is because either B, before

beginning to tango, will be able to correctly assess A's

creditworthiness in all future states of the world and make sure it

holds enough net real assets to back its promises to pay, or the rising

costs that A faces in financing its portfolio positions will force it

to diversify away its risk until the previous condition is in fact met,

i.e. A has enough real equities to pay for its derivative commitments

in case those come due and X (i.e. shit, for those that just tuned in)

happens. Because economic theorists studying financial markets almost

always assume these conditions to be satisfied, the fear that point 1

raises in the layman was not shared, until now, by financial economists.


Which begs the next question: along which dimensions did actual US

financial markets violate the assumptions above? How about "all, and

then some"? While I believe that "some" is the key, let me go through

"all" first.

'<h' . (('4') + 1) . '>' '</h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'

'<h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'Earth is, indeed, different from the standard model'</h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'

We teach that financial markets serve two purposes. They allow society

to transfer resources from those who did the saving to those that would

like to do the investing, which is good. We also teach that financial

markets arrange transactions shifting the bearing of risks from those

who do not want them to those who want them, in exchange for a fee. The

latter function is considered of the utmost importance by financial

economists, who spend a large amount of time showing how risk-bearing

is reduced as financial markets become more "complete" - i.e. more

independent securities are created; derivatives have been shown to be

able to play a key role in this beneficial process - and economic

allocations more efficient, in the sense of Pareto. An important caveat

here is that we assume that there are two kinds of risks: the

individual or diversifiable one (I gain, you lose) and the aggregate or

undiversifiable one (we lose, or gain, together). While financial

markets are magically capable of "dissolving" the first kind of risk,

they cannot do the same for the second. The second is just shifted from

one person to another in exchange for a fee, but the grand total

remains constant independently of how many fancy securities there are

out there. Let's keep this in mind.


We never teach that financial markets can be used to take bets, but

this is what the second function implies. If A transfers some aggregate

risk to B, then A may believe to be safer because B is now bearing its

burden. But this is not really true unless B is capable, and willing,

to cover the risk by means of actual equities, should the downside

event take place. Hence, as before in point 1, risk-shifting is bounded

by the total amount of resources available at any given point in time

and, specifically, is bounded by the amount of actual equities the

seller of insurance owns relative to the insurance it promised through

derivative contracts. If you think of it this way, the whole thing

becomes quite obvious, no? That's why, traditionally, we (i.e. the

regulators and independent overseers that are supposed to act on behalf

of citizens) make sure that insurance companies own lots of big and

fancy buildings, good land, safe stock, oil fields, and so on ...

pretty much like AIG did, right? Let us keep also this in mind.


Now, let me go back to my old example of A, B, C, etc. and make it a

bit closer to what we are talking about. In the updated story B is a

bank, holding a mortgage of $100 on a house with a market value of

$111. B may have purchased that mortgage from someone else, which

originated that mortgage by assessing incorrectly the risk that the

borrower may default ... or which may have made a small - and for sure

unintentional - mistake when typing in the income of the borrower in

the loan application form (say, $70 instead of $50, which makes a big

difference for the implied probability of defaulting ...). This does

not matter at this point: clearly LOTS of things like these happened

in the US mortgage market between 2000 and 2006, but our focus here is

on the continuation. Hence, B values the mortgage at $100 on the asset

side of its books, posting $100 in own capital on the other side, and

nothing else. The banker running B feels there is a 50% probability

that the borrower will default, in which case, via the foreclosure

process, it would end up receiving only $50. B does not like to hold

this risk, as it means that its net capital is really only $75 (i.e.

$100 - 50x0.5), while the shareholders will approve the banker's hefty

bonus of $15 only if net capital is at least $90. Hence B goes to A and

buys insurance, say in the form of a CDS,

promising to pay $90 no matter what in exchange for the proceedings

from the mortgage. You may ask if A is stupid or something, and the

short answer is "no". Clearly, something is happening here that is

creating a profit, for B, of $15 out of thin air: the mortgage has an

expected value of $75, so why should A promise B $90 for sure? There

are various explanations for this, all of which I believe apply to the

US 2000-2008. Here they are:


1. A assigns only a probability of 20% to the default event. People

make random mistakes, we assume, so there are equally as many As assigning a probability of 80% to the default event. But

these two groups do not cancel out because the first will

sell insurance whereas the second will do nothing. Think of this kind

of As as comprising all the "dumb/unlucky guys" that are always around

financial markets but become particularly frequent when the market is

bully.


2. B intentionally packages the mortgage in some "vehicle" that is

confusing enough to lead A to believe it is better than it is. Indeed,

this is

what private information means, in this world! Think of these As as

those guys that said "oops, we did not know what we had purchased",

like UBS or SG.


3. A's own capital is only $4, which it will not mind losing should the

default occur: 10/2 -4/2 = 3, which means a positive expected profits.

Assume A is an investment bank, or an insurer, and pick your name among

the now famous ones.


4. A is "betting" by taking up risk that cannot be diversified because

it goes always the same way. For example, it may be purchasing very many

of these mortgages (at a price of $90) by borrowing on the

money market or issuing bonds. A (or should I call it F&F?) pays very low interest rates because markets perceive the Federal Government is backing A's liabilities.


5. The interbank market is flooded with liquidity at a very low nominal

rate, say 1.5%. A cannot find any liquid security paying a decent

return, while these deals on mortgages are liquid and seem to be paying

a hefty return as long as the borrowers do not default. Call A

Countriwide.


6. There is another character, called A', from which A plans to buy

insurance against the risk of losing $40 in case of default. The

character called A' satisfies one or more of the characteristics 1.-5.

and charges $8 for this.


7. Repeat 6. as many times as you please, because the OTC derivatives

market, which is neither regulated nor centrally organized, allows you

to do so. All you need is that S&P, Moodys and friends keep saying

you are a great credit. You pay their fees, so chances are they will.


Let me take home my second point.


Actual financial markets are much more imperfect than our

theoretical models, whose crucial assumptions are often violated. This

is well known, and things have always been like this, hence per se this

is not big deal. What the existence of an unregulated OTC derivatives

market plagued by private information allows is to leverage these

common "frictions" dozens of time, creating, under the appropriate

circumstances, a snowball that is, indeed quite big. Call this point 2.

'<h' . (('4') + 1) . '>' '</h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'

'<h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'All assumptions are violated, and then some'</h' . (('4') + 1) . '>'

Let me conclude for today with the "some" that, in my opinion, happens

to be the crucial one. That is: if point 3, coming next, had not been

true the fact that points 1 and 2 were would have created some

problems, but not the disaster we are apparently facing. It would have

been, in other words, business as usual on Wall Street.


The key thing is that the probability of default on nominal loans with

variable rates (and mortgages are nominal loans with, in recent years,

very variable rates) is endogenous. It depends, first and foremost, on

the nominal interest rate applied to the loan, which, in turn, depends

on the nominal interest rate clearing the short term interbank markets

that, in turn, is controlled by the Federal Funds rate. When those

rates are low the rates on mortgages are low and liquidity is abundant:

very many mortgages are issued and, if one has reasons to believe that

the short term rates will stay low for quite a while, it is reasonable

to expect the default rates will remain low. When those nominal rates

increase, and nominal incomes do not increase likewise, the probability

of default on those mortgages increases. This is what happened in the US during the 2001-2007 period due to the Federal Reserve "countercyclical" monetary policy.


Now, this is pretty normal and if those mortgages were held by the

banks that had issued them and the latter had not yet "taken profits"

on those mortgages, they would have set aside capital reserves to cover those

losses. This is what is currently happening in Spain that has also seen

a gigantic (in fact, proportionally much bigger than the US one) real

estate boom (1997-2006) followed by a bust in the last two years. In

Spain default rates on mortgages have tripled and interest rates have increased but, because (a) most

mortgages are held by the banks that issued them, and neither (b) have

been heavily securitized through derivatives nor, (c) have the "nominal

profits" on those derivatives been cashed-in (either in the form of

dividends or gigantic bonuses to the investment bankers) the financial

system is very far from coming apart. In fact, it posted record profits

even during the first semester of 2008, which I find rather surprising.

In other words, for reasons that should by now be clear, the "nominal

profits from derivatives issuing and trading" were not "taken" but set

aside till the end of the life of the underlying mortgages. The

opposite happened in the US.


What happened in the US, then? Simple: a derivative is a contract that

involves a sequence of payments over a period of time. If you make real

profits or not from a given derivative contract can be decided only

once the derivative expires and the whole sequence of implied payments

has been settled. But the current functioning of the OTC derivative

market allows something different to happen. Using our simple example,

here's the story. A mortgage is issued that, at current nominal rates,

has a low probability of default. Insuring it is cheap and, by

securitizing it, profits can be taken right away as the financing of

the security is obtained at low nominal rates, insurance is cheap and

the mortgage is off our hands in three days. This is quite fine, if the

probability of default on that mortgage does not change due to altered (by the Fed's actions) conditions in the borrowing and

lending markets. Should conditions remain constant, those initial

profits would correspond to actual profits also at expiration. But in

the meanwhile interest rates increase and default rates raise

accordingly. This means that the derivative security linked to the

underlying mortgage is actually loosing value and its prices should

drop. But you have it in the book for 100 and writing it down to 80

is a problem, so for a while you borrow on the money market to finance

the payments that, for example, the CDS you signed on forces you to.

The opacity of the OTC markets allows you to do so, maybe by entering in

even more derivative contracts. This goes on as long as you appear to be

credit worthy to the counterparts, which is not forever. In the

meanwhile pseudo profits are made, dividends are paid (these are

peanuts) and bonuses are also paid to you (these are not peanuts). From

the point of view of the theory this is money that should "stay in" (in

the form of capital reserves of the investment bank or the insurer underwriting

the CDS) to cover (via its capitalization at risk-adjusted market

rates) for possible future losses. But this is not what happened: the

capital reserves to cover future losses did not "stay in", they went

out to the mansion in the Hamptons. Call this point 3.


When shit hits the fan, oops X happens, you have no capital reserves, hence you

are not credit worthy, hence no one lend to you and you are maybe

insolvent and certainly illiquid. Hence you go the way of Bear Sterns

or Lehman Brothers ...


To quote, with a small [alteration], Robert Solow:


 

[...] the hedge-fund operators [read: investment bankers] and

others [fill in the name of your preferred banker] may earn perfectly

enormous incomes. (Margaret Blair of the Brookings Institution was one

of the first to point this out.) If they are clever enough, and they

are, they can arrange their compensation packages so that they batten

on profits and are shielded from losses.

 


This is because, in the actual financial environment of USA 2001-2008,

(pseudo) profits from derivatives came earlier - when interest rates

were low, hence expected default rates were low - and (very real)

losses came later - when interest rates increased, hence actual default

rates also did - and had to be absorbed by the little capital left in

the firm, which was not enough. The actual capital reserves had been

taken out by calling them "profits". This is point 3 again, only shortened.


Because it is late, I hope it is now clear why it took the convergence

of all three contingencies, summarized as points 1, 2 and 3, for this

disaster to happen. Any two of them without the third would have not, I

believe, caused the big mess we are currently into.

In this sense this

is an "exceptional event", and it needs not imply the "end of capitalism". But, in an another sense, it is and was a

perfectly predictable event: various people wiser than myself (e.g. Mr.

Warren Buffett) had pretty much predicted it a few years back. We, the academic economists, were blind to the facts and did not see it happening because we assumed the deviations of reality from our "standard model" to be quantitatively small. We were mostly wrong, and a few wiser people were right. More than anything, though, I believe we did not see that the particular nature of derivative contracts (their being "zero sum games, if no one cheats") together with the private information that plagues the OTC derivative markets allowed for gigantic (pseudo) profits-taking of funds that were, according to the theory and should have been in fact, capital reserves that had to be "left in the firm" to serve until the life of the derivative contract. But derivative contracts, these misterious zero net supply securities, allow for redistributing wealth from B to A at points in time that preceed their expiration, and redistributing to oneself very large sums of money (in a perfectly "legal" way) is a temptation no one can easily resist. Investment bankers may not be wizards, as they often portray themselves, but they are certainly humans.

Quite

correctly bygones are bygones and, in the unlikely event this

analysis will be found convincing, it still does not tell us what to do

NOW given the current circumstances. In particular, should we go the way that

Bernanke and Paulson are pushing us to go? Is there another and better

way? I am not sure, but I believe a narrow but clear other way can be

found on the basis of this analysis and similar ones developed by other. To the issue of "WHAT TO DO NOW" I hope to turn soon in the third part of these thoughts.

 

Indietro

Commenti

Ci sono 36 commenti

Caro Michele, davvero complimenti. Chiaro ed esauriente, come al solito, anzi più del solito. Solo due brevi commenti:

1. non mi pare di aver letto nel tuo post che le decisioni della Fed sul tasso di interesse sono prese guardando anche (soprattutto?) all'economia reale, non solo alla pura finanza dei derivatives. Questo spiega perché può verificarsi una politica monetaria che oggettivamente si trova prima ad edificare e poi (doverosamente?) a bruciare la gigantesca piramide di carta che così bene descrivi. L'inevitabile doppio ruoli della liquidità, ovvero finanziare l'economia reale delle equities e alimentare la piramide dei derivatives, è a mio avviso un aspetto essenziale della questione.

2. le tue ammissioni sul "fallimento" degli economisti ti fanno onore. Scherzando un po', potrei chiederti se hai iniziato ad indossare calzini a pois e/o pensi di riciclarti come commercialista in Valtellina... Più seriamente, mi piacerebbe una discussione con te ed altri (non in questo post, però) sulle responsabilità della formazione accademica degli operatori finanziari alla luce di tue affermazioni tipo:

 

Because economic theorists studying financial markets almost always assume these conditions to be satisfied, the fear that point 1 raises in the layman was not shared, until now, by financial economists.

 

 

We, the academic economists, were blind to the facts and did not see it happening because we assumed the deviations of reality from our "standard model" to be quantitatively small. We were mostly wrong, and a few wiser people were right.

 

Non credi che un po' più di storia economica (e magari anche di storia della teoria economica), e un po' meno di fancy math, avrebbe potuto insegnare qualcosa ai rampanti banchieri USA when still in their business school? Oppure, it's only a matter of regulation failure?

 

 

It would be good to start part III by briefly describing what would happen if the US Gov does not intervene.

 

I admit that I have carefully read only the first part of the story. The have had only a quick look at the second part. I have the impression that Michele is partially missing the main point.

The core of the picture that he is outlining is that OTC derivatives are the main culprits for what is currently happening. Surely he knows that he is not the only one supporting this argument. I remember that George Soros and, in Italy, Guido Rossi were also blaming the size of OTC derivative market (OTC Credit Default Swaps on the top). They say: derivatives are non trasparent and allow dealers to cheat (each other ? or the public opinion ?). I dare say that the first point has been already addressed by OTC derivative dealer since several years through collateral agreements. The  counterparties of  OTC deals agree to check jointly, on a daily basis, the evaluation of the  contracts they have traded (note that these contracts are not all long or all short but somewhat balanced) and the one which is net debtor will provide some cash collateral in order to mitigate counterparty (i.e. credit) risk. In case two dealers are pricing the same contract in two different ways they have a strong incentive to check their pricing models.

OTC derivatives look much like a scapegoat rather than a culprit. The current crisis is mainly related to something else: asset backed securities and the like (which in their more sophisticated forms include derivative components as well). Together with leverage well beyond safe levels. What were doing regulators in the meanwhile ? Looking at the bright side (conspicuos profits that banks were gaining until one a half year ago, you know money is always right). What were doing rating agencies ? Making money through commissions generated by new and new issues of ABSs (that were eventually repackaged into new things and new ABS backed securities). Where did rating agencies indipendency go ? Gone (at a fair price though). Almost everybody was on board. Well, a proper explanation require much more time and words. But this is the substance.

What else ? The main director of  the bailout is going to be Mr. Paulson. Actually it seems they are deciding to give the key of the stable to the wolf himself. No doubt he is a smart guy. No doubt about who he will favour when facing the choice between taxpayer interest and Wall Street (i.e. Goldman Sachs) interest. I suppose that in comparison the well known conflict of interest of Mr. Silvio Berlusconi will pale. One question arise. If the money of all can be used to back heavily a few, what can be said when the most will try to seize the richness of the few ?

 

 

We essentially agree, Amadeus, but let me try to clarify in three steps.

First, I agree with you that,

 

The current crisis is mainly related to something else: asset backed

securities and the like (which in their more sophisticated forms

include derivative components as well). Together with leverage well

beyond safe levels. What were doing regulators in the meanwhile ?

Looking at the bright side (conspicuos profits that banks were gaining

until one a half year ago, you know money is always right). What were

doing rating agencies ? Making money through commissions generated by

new and new issues of ABSs (that were eventually repackaged into new

things and new ABS backed securities). Where did rating agencies

indipendency go ? Gone (at a fair price though). Almost everybody was

on board. Well, a proper explanation require much more time and words.

But this is the substance.

 

I thought this is what my example and all the "violations of the standard model" I describe are  meant to say. If, after all those words, I did not succeed, I should reconsider my writing.

BUT, and this is the second point, without the use of a very large amount of OTC derivatives ($60 trilion only in CDSs) the whole packaging and siphoning around of ABSs would have been much harder, if not impossible. First because a lot of that took place in the form of derivatives and, second and more important, because all the (pseudo, ex-post) insuring of the underlying risk would have been impossibile.

Finally, and it is my third, without the "smart pricing" of derivatives, the economically unjustified "profits taking" activity that has turned the now so needed capital reserves into mansions in the Hamptons, airplanes and trophy wifes, would have been impossible. And most of the collapses we are witnessing would have not happened.

I am not trying to make the OTC market the culprit of the whole story! Far from me. When I write that all three conditions are needed for such a mess to happen, I strictly mean it: what a triple witch decade this is! 

Finally, one must accept that some observations are correct even if they force us to agree with characters we do not find particularly admirable, e.g. Mr. Soros. You mention all these good measures taken on the OTC markets: correct. Still, after the fact it is easy to see that they must have been pretty ineffective if hundred of billions in CDS contracts are being defaulted upon. Evidently the various parties had not carefully and daily checked the credit worthiness of the various counterparties, no? Again, the OTC market is not the culprit but it is hard to deny it is one of them. 

 

 

OTC derivatives look much like a scapegoat rather than a culprit. The

current crisis is mainly related to something else: asset backed

securities and the like (which in their more sophisticated forms

include derivative components as well). Together with leverage well

beyond safe levels. What were doing regulators in the meanwhile ?

Looking at the bright side (conspicuos profits that banks were gaining

until one a half year ago, you know money is always right). What were

doing rating agencies ? Making money through commissions generated by

new and new issues of ABSs (that were eventually repackaged into new

things and new ABS backed securities). Where did rating agencies

indipendency go ? Gone (at a fair price though). Almost everybody was

on board. Well, a proper explanation require much more time and words.

But this is the substance.

 

Gia', ma la colpa a ben guardare non e' neppure loro:

- Le rating agencies facevano quello che uno si aspetta da ogni entita' privata, cioe' massimizzare i profitti per il loro azionisti: fidarsene come se fossero imparziali e' da ingenui se fatto da investitori privati, e pura follia se fatto da istituzioni pubbliche come la BIS (su questo, vedi l'opinione che esprimevo poco piu' di un anno fa).

- I regolatori, poi, facevano quello che gli era stato detto di fare, guardando al proprio cortile e ignorando quello accanto. Ad esempio, se la FED per statuto non era responsabile per la supervisione ne' delle banche d'investimento ne' delle assicurazioni come AIG (o MBIA e Ambac, altri disastri in attesa di succedere di cui ora tutti sembrano essersi dimenticati), non le si puo' far carico di essersi addormentata al volante.

Le responsabilita' semmai ricadono su chi definisce i compiti e i poteri dei regolatori, cioe' dei rappresentanti democraticamente eletti a Presidenza e Congresso: i quali in questi giorni, sia a destra che a sinistra, si atteggiano invece ad autentici difensori del pubblico interesse nello stile del capitano Renault di Casablanca ("I'm shocked, shocked to find that gambling is going on in here!", salvo intascare un secondo dopo i proventi delle sue vincite - are you listening, Robert "Citi" Rubin?). 

 

I'll write this in my laughable Italian. Apologies. Ovviamente qualcosa va fatto per evitare il disastro del sistema finanziario americano, ci sono due aspetti che però trovo in un certo senso divertenti:

1) Il piano del Tesoro, per quello che ne capisce, prevede che il congresso firmi un assegno in bianco al Ministro delle Finanze (che come avete ricordato è un ex Goldman Sachs). A confronto, l'intervento per salvare Alitalia sembra essere ispirato da Von Hayek. Nella 'socialista' Unione Europea un intervento di stato di questo tipo non sarebbe mai stato ammesso anche perchè, a occhio, fa a cazzotti col potere di controllo che il Parlamento dovrebbe avere col Governo.

2) Dopo i ripetuti salvataggi di istituzioni finanziarie il rischio sovrano degli Stati Uniti è aumentato: di conseguenza il prezzo delle obbligazioni pubbliche già emesse scenderà. Dato che una parte consistente del debito estero statunitense è finanziato da acquisti esteri di obbligazioni e azioni, la discesa dei prezzi dei treasuries, unita al deprezzamento del dollaro e alla caduta dei prezzi di borsa, equivale a un parziale default del debito estero.

Se ci pensate, tutto questo è tipicamente americano, se solo si considera la parte di continente a Sud del Rio Grande: lì i Governi intervenivano (e in parte inteverngono ancora ) massicciamente nell'economia passando sopra al parlamento, e ogni tanto, quanto la situazione va fuori controllo, decidono di non pagare più di debiti. Bienvenidos a Latinoamerica, queridos Yanquis! 

 

 

 

If I get the point the key is how bad unregulated, well ill-regulated, markets perform (i.e OTC). Nihil sub sole novum. Few years ago Enron went bankrupt using similar tricks. Now we running across this same situation again. But Lehman, Fannie, Freddie and AIG make Enron look like a lemonade stand.

 

 

can't wait for the third episode.

[now, if michele was a seasoned pusher he would charge us for the third part. i claim intellectual property rights on this idea, hence sharing of profits if implemented]

 

A me sembra di essere tornato all'Università , grazie Michele per avermi tolto vent'anni in un colpo solo, anche il racconto a puntate mi ha ricordato il mio professore di Economia Politica (Mariano D'Antonio, Keynesiano, da sei mesi assessore "tecnico" nella Giunta Regionale Campana di Bassolino, attento Michele, è una fine che non auguro a nessuno), che arrivato sul più bello ci diceva: "il resto a domani e studiatevi la curva di domanda !"

Attendo le tue conclusioni, le mie per quel che valgono sono: salvare F&F ed il resto che vada in malora ! Tra l'altro concordo con Oronzo Canà (il proprio nome no?) che tutti quelli che hanno titoli del Tesoro Americano rischiano una bella svalutazione, ma non è la prima volta che gli USA fanno pagare ad altri i propri debiti.

 

Oggi alcuni benestanti amerikani hanno ricevuto questo messaggio di e-mail. L'ho ricevuto anche io, purtroppo ... Che sia spam?

 

From: Minister of the Treasury Paulson
Subject: REQUEST FOR URGENT CONFIDENTIAL BUSINESS RELATIONSHIP
Dear American:
I need to ask you to support an urgent secret business relationship with a
transfer of funds of great magnitude.
I am Ministry of the Treasury of the Republic of America. My country has had
crisis that has caused need for large transfer of funds of 700 billion
dollars US. If you would assist me in this transfer, it would be most
profitable to you.
I am working with Mr. Phil Gramm, lobbyist for UBS, who will be my
replacement as Ministry of the Treasury in January. As a Senator, you may
know him as the leader of the American banking deregulation movement in the
1990s. This transactin is 100% safe.
This is a matter of great urgency. We need blank check. We need funds as
quickly as possible. We cannot directly transfer funds in the names of our
close friends because we are constantly under surveillance. My family lawyer
advised me that I should look for reliable and trustworthy person who will
act as a next of kin so funds can be transferred.
Please reply with all of your bank account, IRA and college fund account
numbers and those of your children and grandchildren to
wallstreetbailout@treasury.gov so that we may transfer your commission for
this transaction. After I receive confirmation of transfer, I will respond
with detailed information about safeguards that will be used to protect the
funds.
Yours Faithfully Minister of Treasury Paulson

 

 

 

... ma temo che verra' trattata come tale dal signore che ha inviato la precedente.  Io, comunque, l'ho firmata, assieme a molti altri colleghi ...

 

To the Speaker of the House of Representatives and the President pro tempore of the
Senate:
As economists, we want to express to Congress our great concern for the plan
proposed by Treasury Secretary Paulson to deal with the financial crisis. We are
well aware of the difficulty of the current financial situation and we agree with
the need for bold action to ensure that the financial system continues to function.
We see three fatal pitfalls in the currently proposed plan:
1) Its fairness. The plan is a subsidy to investors at taxpayers'expense. Investors
who took risks to earn profits must also bear the losses.  Not every business
failure carries "systemic risk." The government can ensure a well-functioning
financial industry, able to make new loans to creditworthy borrowers, without
bailing out particular investors and institutions whose choices proved unwise.
2) Its ambiguity. Neither the mission of the new agency nor its oversight are clear.
If  taxpayers are to buy illiquid and opaque assets from troubled sellers, the
terms, occasions, and methods of such purchases must be crystal clear ahead of time
and carefully monitored afterwards.
3) Its long-term effects.  If the plan is enacted, its effects will be with us for a
generation. For all their recent troubles, America's dynamic and innovative private
capital markets have brought the nation unparalleled prosperity.  Fundamentally
weakening those markets in order to calm short-run disruptions is desperately
short-sighted.
For these reasons we ask Congress not to rush, to hold appropriate hearings, and to
carefully consider the right course of action. The manifest intention to intervene
has already calmed the markets and given us all the opportunity to wisely determine
the future of the financial industry and the U.S. economy for years to come.

 

 

 

 

 

Investors

who took risks to earn profits must also bear the losses. Not every

business failure carries “systemic risk”.

 

 

 Bisognerebbe

spiegarlo anche a chi, nella terra di Pantalone, va cianciando di

risarcimenti ai cosiddetti "piccoli investitori .....

<em>

<em>


 

 

... di questa lettera a Paulson comprende il gotha dell'economia accademica attuale, io credo che qualche effetto avrà. Ieri Paulson è stato massacrato dai lawmakers, dovrà per forza di cose trattare. Il problema è capire se la trattativa andrà nella giusta direzione; dalle premesse e dalle cose lette in giro, mi pare di no, per cui tenere alta la pressione dell'opinione pubblica mi pare necessario, e questa lettera va in quella direzione.

 

Segnalo questo articolo di Mario Seminerio che trovo "abbastanza" sconvolgente, esp. per quanto riguarda l'Europa.

 

 

Segnalo questo articolo di Mario Seminerio che trovo "abbastanza" sconvolgente, esp. per quanto riguarda l'Europa.

 

Vedi anche quest'articolo di  Daniel Gros e Stefano Micossi, pubblicato in inglese anche sul Financial Times.

 

Copio e incollo dal sito www.electoral-vote.com. Devo dire che l'esatta indicazione di ''bailouts of private institutions'' è impressionante. Che un partito faccia cose diverse da quelle dette nel programma non è così strano, nemmeno negli Stati Uniti, ma che lo faccia addirittura in campagna elettorale lascia un po' interdetti.

 

The Republican Party

platform adopted 3 weeks ago

explicitly opposes government bailouts of private companies. Here is the exact quote (from the section

"Rebuilding Homeownership"):

We do not support government bailouts of private institutions.

Government interference in the markets exacerbates problems in the marketplace and causes the

free market to take longer to correct itself. We believe in the free market as the best tool to

sustained prosperity and opportunity for all.

This plank in the GOP platform is not controversial within the party. Republicans have always believed that

when companies make bad business decisions the market will punish them and this is the deterrence for future

companies to think through their decisions carefully. The problem now is the utter hypocrisy of throwing

overboard a principle Republicans have held dear for a century.

If (big) companies lose the fear of bankruptcy because they expect the government to bail them out, they will take

unconscionable risks in the future. Maybe somebody should send Henry Paulson a copy of the Republican platform.

 

Maybe this is a little offtopic, but when I read point 3 I think about all the news about local italian governments making heavy use of derivatives.With little changes, the short version might become:

 

[...] the hedge-fund operators [read: mayors and governors] and

others [fill in the name of your preferred banker] may earn [spend] perfectly

enormous incomes [amounts]. (Margaret Blair of the Brookings Institution was one

of the first to point this out.) If they are clever enough, and they

are, they can arrange their compensation packages so that they batten

on profits and are shielded from losses [which will come after the end of their mandate].

 

I'm not sure if point 1 and 2 hold in this case, but my guess is that 1 does and 2 might be replaced by the implicit state warranty on local debt.

Should we expect a similar scenario in our  local governments?

 

Absolutely yes. Italian local governments, as documented in a past episode of Report on Rai3, have been exploiting derivatives offered to them by Italian and foreign banks, which were designed to give them money in the present and in the next few years of their mandate, while shifting all the duties and the reinboursements to after their present mandate. To add spice, the amount of money given to them by the banks now is about certain and does not reflect market fluctuations, while the money they have to return eventually is much larger than the one they should have returned by issuing ordinary bonds and furthermore it is significantly affected by market fluctuations. Often the risk of market fluctuations is entirely charged on the (stupid) Italian local governemnts, while the banks could not possibly loose because of market fluctuations. Of course the banks quite safely bet on the fact that the Italian central government will at all costs back up bankrupt local governments no matter how stupid, incompetent dishonest and corrupt they were. At some time, the Italian central government adopted regulations thar were intended to prevent local governments signing derivaties that were not centrally scrutinized and approved.